Singh And Stella on Collateral
A recent paper by
Manmohan Singh and Peter Stella for the IMF Research Department (blogged
version here) makes an
interesting contribution to begin by questioning the money multiplier – one of
the key concepts concerning how central banks are supposed to work.
Traditionally, they point out, “credit and money are
[considered] counterparts to each other on different sides of the balance sheet”:
banks create credit backed by the ‘base money’ which they hold as currency or
deposits with the central bank. The money multiplier is the ratio of total
monetary liabilities in the economy (the loans extended by the banking system)
divided by the monetary base. With bank notes removed from the equation leaving
only the ‘liquid reserves’ which banks have deposited with the central bank,
the adjusted money multiplier is
considered to provide a measure of the performance (or risk) of the commercial
banking system in providing credit to the economy.
Through their ability to create or withdraw these reserves
of base money by buying and selling financial assets from commercial banks (known
as ‘open market operations’)
the central banks are commonly considered to control a ‘transmission mechanism’
which determines the money multiplier. To increase the supply of money in the
economy, the central bank can buy financial assets from commercial banks in exchange
for liquid central bank deposits, which should provide the basis for increased
lending both between commercial banks and into the wider non financial economy
(the exact quantity of which should be predictable through algebra): QE has
essentially been this carried out on a vast scale, and it is why many financial
commentators assert that the measures will inevitably create
hyperinflation.
The paper challenges these notions, firstly by pointing out
the by now well known fact that in the decades leading up to the financial
crisis, the total amount of credit in the US economy increased far faster than
the creation of new central bank deposits (see figure 2). Why? Only commercial
banks can hold deposits at the central bank, but as the authors point out over
the past 30 years the shadow banking system “has accounted for almost the entire growth in US
financial deepening”.
How? Though the use of liquid assets to be used in collateralized borrowing:
highly rated securities can be used again and again as collateral for the
creation of new loans in a process called re-hypothecation, and the increased
use of securitization created a range of new alternative liquid assets to be
used by the shadow banking system to create loans.
Distinctions
need to be made between different types of collateral. On the one hand there is
high quality collateral in the form of bonds issued by solvent sovereign
governments, which can be used in credit creation almost anywhere. Other kinds
of securities can be used as collateral under normal market conditions (and
their use grew enormously in the run up to 2008) but they lose their utility in
this regard in a downturn when markets begin to doubt their value. This
happened most spectacularly with securitized housing market assets, resulting
in a system wide liquidity crisis as interbank lending seized up.
The real fulcrum of liquidity creation, they argue, is to be
found in the market practices relating to judgements of which assets are
‘acceptable collateral’ rather than with the central bank officials executing
conventional monetary policy. Since the crisis, this has been reflected in two
phenomena. Firstly, there has been intense demand for safe assets to use as
collateral – hence the low price of UK and US government borrowing despite
their indebtedness. Secondly, despite the unprecedented creation of new
reserves at the Fed, there has been no corresponding increase in inflation (see
table 1).
Since the crisis, chains of re-pledging have shortened from
3 steps in 2007 to 2.4 at the end of 2010, while the total volumes of
re-pledged collateral have fallen from $10 trillion in 2007 to $5.8 trillion at
the end of 2010. The actions taken by central banks in expanding their balance
sheets has not, the authors suggest, been sufficient to make up for these
losses: conventional QE substituted central bank deposits for high quality
collateral that would have been re-pledged for collateralized borrowing,
meaning that QE had nothing like the lubricating effect on the financial system
that would have been anticipated under a conventional money multiplier view.
The banks’ liquidity crisis continues and, as the authors
note
Unless there is some rebound
in the pledgeable collateral market (by either an increase in ‘source’
collateral, or its velocity or re-use rate), the likely asymmetry in the demand
and supply of good collateral may entail some difficult choices for the markets
and the regulators.
Difficult choices such as whether a return to pre-crisis
levels of global liquidity is even possible, let alone desirable.
Monetary policy is in uncharted territory and, they argue,
as assumptions about the relative importance of the transmission mechanism
against the role of collateral are revised, swapping bad for good collateral
may now become a routine activity of central banks. This carries with it
questions of risk and accountability which make the independence of central
banks from democratic accountability seem more problematic than ever.
No comments:
Post a Comment